UNDERSTANDING MONEY IN EARLY AMERICAN LITERATURE.

If you read the literature of the young United States, you have doubtless been puzzled when the subject of money comes up. Shillings, eagles, dollars, half-johanneses, dimes, pistareens—they all seem to mingle indiscriminately in everyone’s purse. Money seems to be a very complicated subject.

In fact it was more complicated than you probably imagined. The federal government had its currency in dollars (ten dollars made an eagle), but the states had their own coinage in pounds, shillings, and pence, and the values were different from state to state. There were four different systems of values among the original thirteen states two hundred years ago. (State coins in pounds, shillings, and pence were no longer issued after 1793, but they remained in circulation for decades after that.) Furthermore, much of the money in circulation at the time was foreign: the Spanish milled dollar was the basis of the American dollar, and British, French, Spanish, and Portuguese coins all jingled in an American purse.

Fortunately we have this chart, published in Pittsburgh exactly two hundred years ago, that compares the values of the various coins an American might use.

The values for state coinage are given in pounds, shillings, and pence; the values for federal coinage are given in eagles, dollars, dimes, cents, and tenths of cents.

The same book explains at length how to convert the coinage of one state to another’s—an explanation that takes up two pages: “To reduce Pennsylvania, New Jersey, Delaware and Maryland, into New Hampshire, Massachusetts, Rhode Island, Connecticut and Virginia, from the sum given deduct 1/5 thereof. Into New York and North Carolina, to the sum given add 1/15 thereof. Into South Carolina and Georgia, multiply by 3 and 1/9, and divide the product by 5, or multiply by 28, and divide by 45.” And so on.

On the whole, it is probably a good thing that the states no longer claim the power to coin their own money. 

Comments

  1. Ben Ieghn says:

    Shop-lifting or armed-robbery would seem to be a very reasonable and almost forgivable alternative method of conducting commerce when faced with such a complicated monetary system…can’t you just imagine the lines at the check-out counter?!

    • Sigivald says:

      My understanding was that quite often there would be a scale, and transactions done by weight (with standard purities for the common coinage well known for correction).

      Plus in practice, most people, most of the time, wouldn’t be buying things in gold coin, but in local silver currency.

      A gold dollar or Crown was a considerable amount of money in 1815.

      • Dr. Boli says:

        You are correct that there would often be a scale. Even more often there would not be one, and almost all the coins of the era extant today have been clipped—made slightly smaller by use of shears and file. The filings would be melted down by the unscrupulous clipper and sold for their worth in silver or gold, but the coin would be passed along as if its value were undiminished. The merchants who used scales were using them because they knew how prevalent clipping was; the people doing the clipping were doing it because they knew that most merchants didn’t bother with a scale and would accept the coin at face value.

  2. Nowadays, there would be a smart-phone app to calculate change.

    Some localities in the US have their own currency. I also recall a suggestion in the 1970s that NYC pay off its debt in subway tokens.

    • Ben Ieghn says:

      I’m surprised this solution to NYC fiscal crisis wasn’t fast-tracked; I wonder what de-railed it? I guess they couldn’t get enough folks on-board with the idea…

Leave a Reply to Sigivald Cancel reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *